Print
Article
Volume 3.2
Lawbreaking as Lawmaking
Michael Kang
Class of 1940 Professor of Law, Northwestern Pritzker School of Law.

Many thanks to Richard Briffault, John Coates, Jill Fisch, and Nancy Leong for their comments on an earlier draft.  Thanks also to Zach Furlin, Gene Kim, Brent Larson, and Christine Thomas for excellent research assistance.

Uber has been described by its most extreme critics as “the root of all evil” for its lawbreaking business tactics, among other things, in pursuit of becoming “too big to ban.”

Print
Article
Volume 3.2
Nonprofit Corporations & Politics: The Entity/Coordination Tension
Lloyd Hitoshi Mayer
Professor, Notre Dame Law School.

I am very grateful for the opportunity to participate in this symposium, for the comments and questions from its participants, and for the research assistance of Nathaniel Barry.

Federal tax law treats separate nonprofit corporations as distinct legal entities for almost all purposes, in common with most other areas of law. With respect to political activity, this means that one nonprofit corporation’s lobbying or election-related actions are generally not attributed to another nonprofit corporation.

Print
Comment
Volume 3.2
Twin Inadequacies in the FTC’s Recent Biometrics Policy Statement
John Burroughs
J.D. Candidate 2025, University of Chicago Law School.

Many thanks to Professor Josh Avratin for his invaluable feedback and guidance, and to my family for their constant support. Thank you as well to the University of Chicago Business Law Review editorial staff.

In the spring of 2023, the FTC released a policy statement addressing biometric information and technologies using or purporting to use such information. The policy statement contains a remarkably broad definition of “biometric information” and describes a variety of business practices that could violate § 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act by being either “deceptive” or “unfair.” In spite of the policy statement’s comprehensiveness, however, it has two substantial inadequacies.

Print
Comment
Volume 3.2
Private Equity Investment in Health Care and Ineffective Antitrust Regulations
Sofia Gracias
J.D. Candidate 2025, University of Chicago Law School; MPH 2021, Emory University, Rollins School of Public Health.

The corporatization of health care in the United States has forced us to confront society’s moral expectations of the industry, which serves uniquely vulnerable consumers. Health care has become increasingly more lucrative, attracting private equity (“PE”) investment, specifically in private physicians’ practices.

Print
Comment
Volume 3.2
Free Markets and Free Speech: Understanding the Limits of the Noerr-Pennington Doctrine
Mitsoo K. Patel
B.S. 2019, University of Maryland, College Park; J.D. Candidate 2025, University of Chicago Law School.

Many thanks to the University of Chicago Business Law Review staff for their helpful edits and feedback. I would like to especially thank Professor Eric Posner for his thoughtful suggestions and guidance.

Based in First Amendment principles, the Noerr-Pennington doctrine immunizes parties petitioning the government from antitrust liability, even when such petitioning may be considered anticompetitive. Within the doctrine exists a narrower “sham exception” which eliminates Noerr-Pennington antitrust immunity when petitions are merely shams meant to interfere with a competitor’s business.

Print
Article
Volume 3.1
Can Machines Commit Crimes Under U.S. Antitrust Laws?
Aslihan Asil
Yale University, PhD in Financial Economics 2024, Yale Law School, J.D. 2021

This paper benefitted from discussions with Ian Ayres, Matt Backus, Joe Harrington, Alex MacKay, Fiona Scott Morton, and Paulo Ramos. All errors are the authors’ own. Wollmann thanks the William Ladany Research Fund at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business for its generous support. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Thomas G. Wollmann
Associate Professor of Economics and William Ladany Faculty Scholar, University of Chicago Booth School of Business, Faculty Research Fellow, National Bureau of Economic Research

This paper benefitted from discussions with Ian Ayres, Matt Backus, Joe Harrington, Alex MacKay, Fiona Scott Morton, and Paulo Ramos. All errors are the authors’ own. Wollmann thanks the William Ladany Research Fund at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business for its generous support. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Generative artificial intelligence is being rapidly deployed for corporate tasks including pricing. Suppose one of these machines communicates with the pricing manager of a competing firm, proposes to collude, receives assent, and raises price. Is this a crime under U.S. antitrust laws, and, if so, who is liable?

Print
Article
Volume 3.1
“Killer Acquisitions” Reexamined: Economic Hyperbole in the Age of Populist Antitrust
Jonathan M. Barnett
Torrey H. Webb Professor of Law, Gould School of Law, University of Southern California

I am grateful for comments from Or Brook, Harold Furchgott-Roth, Bo Heiden, Nicolas Petit, Daniel Sokol, David Teece, Selcukhan Unekbas, Matthew Wansley, John Yun, and participants at the European University Institute Competition Law Working Group, the University of Southern California Gould School of Law Faculty Workshop, and the Yale Law School-Hebrew University Law & Economics Conference. This project has been supported by the Berkeley Research Group Institute. Comments are welcome at jbarnett@law.usc.edu.

Major competition regulators, and substantial portions of the scholarly community, have rapidly adopted the view that “killer acquisitions” and “kill zones” constitute significant sources of competitive risk arising from incumbent acquisitions of emerging firms in digital markets. Based on this view, policymakers in the United States, European Union, and other jurisdictions have advocated for, and in some cases have taken, substantial changes to merger review policies that would erect significant obstacles to incumbent/startup acquisitions.

Print
Article
Volume 3.1
Insider Abstention and Rule 10b5-1 Plans
David Rosenfeld
Associate Professor, Northern Illinois University College of Law

I would like to thank Joan Heminway for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this article.

Company insiders will typically be in possession of material non-public information (MNPI) about their companies. In order to allow insiders the opportunity to trade, the SEC adopted Rule 10b5-1, which provides an affirmative defense to insider trading liability if the trades are made pursuant to a written plan or trading instruction entered into when the trader was not aware of MNPI.

Print
Article
Volume 3.1
Corporate Governance and Risk-taking: A Statistical Approach
Steven L. Schwarcz
Stanley A. Star Distinguished Professor of Law & Business, Duke University School of Law; Senior Fellow, the Centre for International Governance Innovation (CIGI); Founding Director, Duke Global Financial Markets Center

The author thanks Stephen M. Bainbridge, Christopher Buccafusco, Elisabeth de Fontenay, John de Figueiredo, Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Lorilee A. Medders and participants in a faculty workshop at Duke University School of Law for valuable comments and Justin Reed and Josh Rudd for invaluable research assistance.

Because prudent corporate governance often requires managers to take risks based on statistically expected outcomes, corporate failures that have a small but finite chance of occurring cannot always be prevented. This Article makes three related claims about risk-taking in corporate governance.

Print
Article
Volume 3.1
The Ascertainable Standards that Define the Boundaries of the SEC’s Rulemaking Authority
Bernard S. Sharfman
Senior Corporate Governance Fellow at the RealClearFoundation; Research Fellow at the Law & Economics Center at George Mason University’s Antonin Scalia Law School; and member of the Journal of Corporation Law’s editorial advisory board

The opinions expressed here are the author’s alone and do not represent the official position of any organization with which he is currently affiliated. Moreover, this Article was not funded by any of the organizations that Mr. Sharfman is affiliated with. Mr. Sharfman would like to thank Amanda Rose, Lawrence A. Cunningham, Bryce Tingle, Alex Platt, and George S. Georgiev for their helpful comments. Mr. Sharfman is dedicating this Article to his wife, Susan Thea David, daughter, Amy David Beltchatovski, son-in-law, Elliot Beltchatovski, and granddaughter, Ava Beltchatovski. The catalyst for this writing was the short discussion of “in the public interest” found in Cass R. Sunstein and Adrian Vermeule’s book, Law & Leviathan: Redeeming the Administrative State 119-122 (2020).

On the heels of the U.S. Supreme Court’s decision in West Virginia v. Environmental Protection Agency, the “major questions” doctrine quickly came to be perceived as a significant impediment to the finalization of the Securities and Exchange Commission’s proposed rule on climate-related disclosures.

Print
Article
Volume 2.2
Antitrust Reform in the Digital Era: A Skeptical Perspective
Robert W. Crandall
Nonresident Senior Fellow, Technology Policy Institute, Washington, DC

rcrandall228@gmail.com

Thomas W. Hazlett
Hugh H. Macaulay Endowed Professor of Economics, Clemson University

hazlett@clemson.edu

The rise of large digital platforms, accompanied by claims of increasing industrial concentration, has prompted calls for antitrust policy reform. Yet, the observed market trends are consistent with improvements in welfare, as economies of scale often decentralize effective choices and disintermediate previously dominant structures, unleashing entrepreneurship.

Print
Article
Volume 2.2
Proceduralism: Delaware’s Legacy
Dalia T. Mitchell
Professor of Law and John Marshall Harlan Dean’s Research Professor of Law, The George Washington University

For their comments on earlier drafts, I am grateful to Harut Minasian, Esq., to participants in a faculty workshop at Rutgers Law School, and to the students in my Fall 2022 Corporations Law seminar. The George Washington University Summer Research Fund provided financial support. All errors are mine.

This article examines the Delaware courts’ 1980s shift from managerialism to a theory I label proceduralism. I argue that managerialism, which justified corporate law’s deference to directors in the preceding fifty years, was corporate law’s response to social, political, and cultural concerns outside corporations.